%!$ Easy Diy Woodworking Bench Plans For You #!@

Things To Build Out At home Part Time

Amana Raised Panel Bits Young,Titebond Ultimate Wood Glue Vs Gorilla Glue Uv,Lathe Tool Post Spanner,Best Drawer Slides For Kitchen Cabinets 30 - Easy Way

amana-raised-panel-bits-young However, there are now a number of careful amana raised panel bits young that suggest that such anecdotes amana raised panel bits young oversold. The unqualified private doctors were by far the worst, particularly those who worked in poor neighborhoods. On arriving there, I found him setting up the stall with our meal kits: boxes with all the fresh ingredients already chopped, washed and Quick steps to Reading and Use of English Part 7 weighed. Many mainstream bands allow their concerts ylung be streamed free of charge. After all, 1, calories is the famous semi-starvation diet, recommended for those who want rapid weight loss; 1, does not seem too far from there. Discipline: Education. Part 3 5 According to Kieran, what mistake do some students 2 Discuss these questions.

We offer essay help for more than 80 subject areas. You can get help on any level of study from high school, certificate, diploma, degree, masters, and Ph. We accept payment from your credit or debit cards. We also accept payment through. PayPal is one of the most widely used money transfer method in the world. It is acceptable in most countries and thus making it the most effective payment method.

We offer free revision in case you are not satisfied with the order delivered to you. For such an order you are expected to send a revision request and include all the instructions that should be followed by the writer. Also remember to state the exact time the writer should take to do your revision. We offer free revision as long as the client does not change the instructions that had been previously given.

In case a client want to alter the instructions, revision can be done but at a negotiated fee. We do not take the issue of plagiarism rightly. As a company we try as much as possible to ensure all orders are plagiarism free. We also have a plagiarism detection system where all our papers are scanned before being delivered to clients.

We have writers who are always ready to work and take up orders with a short deadline. We deliver papers as early as after 3 hours of ordering. You only have to indicate the short deadline and our support team will help pick the best and most qualified writer in your field. The writer will confirm whether they will submit the paper within the set deadline. After confirmation, your paper will be delivered on time.

We never at any time reuse the papers we write for our clients. We also do not have a database of previously written papers. We never send published papers to clients nor do we publish the papers after sending them to our clients. Whether to reference us in your work or not is a personal decision. If it is an academic paper, you have to ensure it is permitted by your institution.

We do not ask clients to reference us in the papers we write for them. When we write papers for you, we transfer all the ownership to you. This means that you do not have to acknowledge us in your work not unless you please to do so. Our online assignment help is one of the best essay writing help in the world as we work with international students from the most prestigious universities in the world.

We write quality papers for our clients as we have employed highly qualified academic writers from all over the world. Our writers are able to handle complex assignments from their field of specialization. When it comes to finding the best specialist for your paper there are 3 categories of specialist that we have to look at;.

Turning to course help online for help is legal. Getting assignment help is ethical as we do not affect nor harm the level of knowledge you are expected to attain as a student according to your class syllabus. Our services are here to provide you with legitimate academic writing help to assist you in learning to improve your academic performance. With course help online, you pay for academic writing help and we give you a legal service. This service is similar to paying a tutor to help improve your skills.

Our online services is trustworthy and it cares about your learning and your degree. Hence, you should be sure of the fact that our online essay help cannot harm your academic life. You can freely use the academic papers written to you as they are original and perfectly referenced. Whenever students face academic hardships, they tend to run to online essay help companies. If this is also happening to you, you can message us at course help online.

We will ensure we give you a high quality content that will give you a good grade. We can handle your term paper, dissertation, a research proposal, or an essay on any topic. We are aware of all the challenges faced by students when tackling class assignments. You can have an assignment that is too complicated or an assignment that needs to be completed sooner than you can manage.

You also need to have time for a social life and this might not be possible due to school work. The good news is that course help online is here to take care of all this needs to ensure all your assignments are completed on time and you have time for other important activities.

We also understand you have a number of subjects to learn and this might make it hard for you to take care of all the assignments. You are expected to do a thorough research for each assignment to earn yourself a good grade even with the limited time you have. This calls upon the need to employ a professional writer. When you employ one of our expert writers, you can be sure to have all your assignments completed on time.

All your assignment deadlines will be met plus you will have an original, non-plagiarized and error free paper.

With our course help online services, you are assured of a completely original and error free paper written exclusively for your specified needs, instructions and requirements. All our papers are original as they are all written from scratch. We also do not re-use any of the papers we write for our customers. With this guarantee feel comfortable to message us or chat with our online agents who are available 24hours a day and 7 days a week be it on a weekend or on a holiday. As a busy student, you might end up forgetting some of the assignments assigned to you until a night or a day before they are due.

This might be very stressing due to inadequate time to do a thorough research to come up with a quality paper. Course help online is here to save you from all this stress. Let our professional writers handle your assignments and submit them to you no matter how close the deadline seems to be. This will protect you from all the pressure that comes along with assignments. You are assured of a high quality assignment that is error free and delivery will be done on time.

We have a reliable team that is always available and determined to help all our clients by improving their grades. We are reliable and trusted among all our clients and thus you can entrust your academic work on us.

For any academic help you need, feel free to talk to our team for assistance and you will never regret your decision to work with us. You can entrust all your academic work to course help online for original and high quality papers submitted on time. We have worked with thousands of students from all over the world. Most of our clients are satisfied with the quality of services offered to them and we have received positive feedback from our clients. We have an essay service that includes plagiarism check and proofreading which is done within your assignment deadline with us.

This ensures all instructions have been followed and the work submitted is original and non-plagiarized. We offer assignment help in more than 80 courses. We are also able to handle any complex paper in any course as we have employed professional writers who are specialized in different fields of study.

From their experience, they are able to work on the most difficult assignments. The following are some of the course we offer assignment help in;. In case you cannot find your course of study on the list above you can search it on the order form or chat with one of our online agents for assistance. We will take care of all your assignment needs We are a leading online assignment help service provider. Place an Order.

Calculate your essay price. Type of paper. Academic level. Pages words. Read more. Plagiarism-free papers To ensure that all the papers we send to our clients are plagiarism free, they are all passed through a plagiarism detecting software. Calculate the price of your order Type of paper needed:. Pages: words. You will get a personal manager and a discount. Academic level:. We'll send you the first draft for approval by September 11, at AM.

Total price:. What advantages do you get from our course help online services? All our academic papers are written from scratch All our clients are privileged to have all their academic papers written from scratch. We do not offer pre-written essays All our essays and assignments are written from scratch and are not connected to any essay database. Urgent orders are delivered on time Do you have an urgent order that you need delivered but have no idea on how to do it?

We provide quality assignment help in any format We have writers who are well trained and experienced in different writing and referencing formats. Order a custom-written paper of high quality.

Order Now or Free Inquiry. How do we ensure our clients are satisfied with our essay writing services? You can have the privilege of paying part by part for long orders thus you can enjoy flexible pricing. We also give discounts for returned customers are we have returned customer discounts.

We also give our clients the privilege of keeping track of the progress of their assignments. You can keep track of all your in-progress assignments. Having many years of experience, we are aware of many things as we have practiced a lot over the time and thus we are able to satisfy our customer needs. The hope, according to the project's Web site, is that "Millennium Village economies can transition over a period from subsistence farming to self-sustaining commercial activity.

There they met Kennedy, a young farmer. He was given free fertilizer, and as a result, the harvest from his field was twenty times what it had been in previous years.

With the savings from that harvest, the video concluded, he would be able to support himself forever. The implicit argument was that Kennedy was in a poverty trap in which he could not afford fertilizer: The gift of fertilizer freed him. It was the only way he could escape from the trap. But, skeptics could object that if fertilizer is really so profitable, why could Kennedy not have bought just a little bit of it and put it on the most suitable part of his field?

This would have raised the yield, and with the extra money generated, he could have bought more fertilizer the following year, and so on. Little by little, he would have become rich enough to be able to put fertilizer on his entire field.

So is Kennedy trapped in poverty, or is he not? The answer depends on whether the strategy is feasible: Buy just a little to start with, make a little extra money, and then reinvest the proceeds, to make even more money, and repeat. But maybe fertilizer is not easy to buy in small quantities.

Or perhaps it takes several tries before you can get it to work. Or there are problems with reinvesting the gains. One could think of many reasons why a farmer might find it difficult to get started on his own.

We will postpone trying to get to the heart of Kennedy's story until Chapter 8. But this discussion helps us see a general principle.

There will be a poverty trap whenever the scope for growing income or wealth at a very fast rate is limited for those who have too little to invest, but expands dramatically for those who can invest a bit more. On the other hand, if the potential for fast growth is high among the poor, and then tapers off as one gets richer, there is no poverty trap. Economists love simple some would say simplistic theories, and they like to represent them in diagrams.

We are no exception: There are two diagrams shown below that we think are helpful illustrations of this debate about the nature of poverty. The most important thing to remember from them is the shape of the curves: We will return to these shapes a number of times in the book. For those who believe in poverty traps, the world looks like Figure 1. Your income today influences what your income will be in the future the future could be tomorrow, next month, or even the next generation : What you have today determines how much you eat, how much you have to spend on medicine or on the education of your children, whether or not you can buy fertilizer or improved seeds for your farm, and all this determines what you will have tomorrow.

The shape of the curve is key: It is very flat at the beginning, and then rises rapidly, before flattening out again.

We will call it, with some apologies to the English alphabet, the S-shape curve. The S-shape of this curve is the source of the poverty trap. On the diagonal line, income today is equal to income tomorrow.

For the very poor who are in the poverty trap zone, income in the future is lower than income today: The curve is below the diagonal line. This means that over time, those in this zone become poorer and poorer, and they will eventually end up trapped in poverty, at point N. The arrows starting at point A1 represent a possible trajectory: from A1, move to A2, and then A3, and so forth. For those who start outside of the poverty trap zone, income tomorrow is higher than income today: Over time they become richer and richer, at least up to a point.

This more cheerful destiny is represented by the arrow starting at point B1, moving to B2 and B3, and so forth. Many economists a majority, perhaps believe, however, that the world usually looks more like Figure 2. Figure 2 looks a bit like the right-hand side of Figure 1, but without the flat left side.

The curve goes up fastest at the beginning, then slower and slower. There is no poverty trap in this world: Because the poorest people earn more than the income they started with, they become richer over time, until eventually their incomes stop This radical shift in perspective, away from the universal answers, required us to step out of the office and look more carefully at the world.

In doing so, we were following a long tradition of development economists who have emphasized the importance of collecting the right data to be able to say anything useful about the world. However, we had two advantages over the previous generations: First, there are now high-quality data from a number of poor countries that were not available before. Second, we have a new, powerful tool: randomized control trials RCTs , which give researchers, working with a local partner, a chance to implement large-scale experiments designed to test their theories.

In an RCT, as in the studies on bed nets, individuals or communities are randomly assigned to different "treatments"-different programs or different versions of the same program. Since the individuals assigned to different treatments are exactly comparable because they were chosen at random , any difference between them is the effect of the treatment.

A single experiment does not provide a final answer on whether a program would universally "work. Together, this allows us to both verify the robustness of our conclusions Does what works in Kenya also work in Madagascar?

Is it the price of fertilizer or the difficulty of saving money? The new theory can help us design interventions and new experiments, and help us make sense of previous results that may have been puzzling before.

Progressively, we obtain a fuller picture of how the poor really live their lives, where they need help, and where they don't. In , we founded the Poverty Action Lab which later became the Abdul Latif Jameel Poverty Action Lab, or J-PAL to encourage and support other researchers, governments, and nongovernmental organizations to work together on this new way of doing economics, and to help diffuse what they have learned among policy makers. The response has been overwhelming.

By , J-PAL researchers had completed or were engaged in over experiments in forty countries around the world, and very large numbers of organizations, researchers, and policy makers have embraced the idea of randomized trials.

The response to J-PAL's work suggests that there are many who share our basic premise-that it is possible to make very significant progress against the biggest problem in the world through the accumulation of a set of small steps, each well thought out, carefully tested, and judiciously implemented. This might seem self-evident, but as we will argue throughout the book, it is not how policy usually gets made.

The practice of development policy, as well as the accompanying debates, seems to be premised on the impossibility of relying on evidence: Verifiable evidence is a chimera, at best a distant fantasy, at worst a distraction. Even today, there are many who hold this view. But there are also many people who have always felt disempowered by this unreasoned urgency. They feel, as we do, that the best anyone can do is to understand deeply the specific problems that afflict the poor and to try to identify the most effective ways to intervene.

In some instances, no doubt, the best option will be to do nothing, but there is no general rule here, just as there is no general principle that spending money always works. It is the body of knowledge that grows out of each specific answer and the understanding that goes into those answers that give us the best shot at, one day, ending poverty.

This book builds on that body of knowledge. A lot of the material that we will talk about comes from RCTs conducted by us and others, but we also make use of many other types of evidence: qualitative and quantitative descriptions of how the poor live, investigations of how specific institutions function, and a variety of evidence on which policies have worked and which have not.

In the companion Web site for the book, www. The studies we use have in common a high level of scientific rigor, openness to accepting the verdict of the data, and a focus on specific, concrete questions of relevance to the lives of the poor. One of the questions that we will use these data to answer is when and where we should worry about poverty traps; we will find them in some areas, but not in others.

In order to design effective policy, it is crucial that we get answers to such questions right. We will see many instances in the chapters that follow where the wrong policy was chosen, not out of bad intentions or corruption, but simply because the policy makers had the wrong model of the world in mind: They thought there was a poverty trap somewhere and there was none, or they were ignoring another one that was right in front of them.

The message of this book, however, goes well beyond poverty traps. As we will see, ideology, ignorance, and inertia-the three Is-on the part of the expert, the aid worker, or the local policy maker, often explain why policies fail and why aid does not have the effect it should. It is possible to make the world a better place-probably not tomorrow, but in some future that is within our reach-but we cannot get there with lazy thinking.

We hope to persuade you that our patient, stepby-step approach is not only a more effective way to fight poverty, but also one that makes the world a more interesting place.

For many of us in the West, poverty is almost synonymous with hunger. Other than major natural catastrophes such as the Boxing Day tsunami in or the Haiti earthquake in , no single event affecting the world's poor has captured the public imagination and prompted collective generosity as much as the Ethiopian famine of the early s and the resulting "We Are the World" concert in March More recently, the announcement by the UN Food and Agriculture Organization FAO in June that more than a billion people are suffering from hunger 1 grabbed the headlines, in a way that the World Bank's estimates of the number of people living under a dollar a day never did.

This association of poverty and hunger is institutionalized in the UN's first Millennium Development Goal MDG , which is "to reduce poverty and hunger. A "poor" person was essentially defined as someone without enough to eat. It is no surprise, therefore, that a large part of governments' effort to help the poor is posited on the idea that the poor desperately need food, and that quantity is what matters. Many states in India have a similar program: In Orissa, for example, the poor are entitled to 55 pounds of rice a month at about 4 rupees per pound, less than 20 percent of the market price.

Currently, the Indian parliament is debating instituting a Right to Food Act, which would allow people to sue the government if they are starving.

The delivery of food aid on a massive scale is a logistical nightmare. In India, it is estimated that more than one-half of the wheat and over one-third of the rice get "lost" along the way, including a good fraction that gets eaten by rats. The intuition is powerful: The poor cannot afford to eat enough; this makes them less productive and keeps them poor. Pak Solhin, who lives in a small village in the province of Bandung, Indonesia, once explained to us exactly how such a poverty trap worked.

His parents used to have a bit of land, but they also had thirteen children and had to build so many houses for each of them and their families that there was no land left for cultivation. However, a recent hike in fertilizer and fuel prices had forced farmers to economize.

According to Pak Solhin, the local farmers decided not to cut wages but to stop hiring workers instead. Pak Solhin became unemployed most of the time: In the two months before we met him in , he had not found a single day of agricultural labor.

Younger people in this situation could normally find work as construction workers. But, as he explained, he was too weak for the most physical work, too inexperienced for more skilled labor, and at forty, too old to be an apprentice: No one would hire him. As a result, Pak Solhin's family-he and his wife, and their three children-were forced to take some drastic steps to survive. His wife left for Jakarta, approximately 80 miles away, where, through a friend, she found a job as a maid.

But she did not earn enough to feed the children. The oldest son, a good student, dropped out of school at twelve and started as an apprentice on a con-struction site. The two younger children were sent to live with their grandparents. Pak Solhin himself survived on about 9 pounds of subsidized rice he got every week from the government and on fish that he caught from the edge of a lake he could not swim.

His brother fed him once in a while. In the week before we last spoke with him, he had had two meals a day for four days, and just one for the other three. Pak Solhin appeared to be out of options, and he clearly attributed his problem to food or, more precisely, the lack of it. It was his opinion that the landowning peasants had decided to fire their workers instead of cutting wages because they thought that with the recent rapid increases in food prices, a cut in wages would push workers into starvation, which would make them useless in the field.

This is how Pak Solhin explained to himself the fact that he was unemployed. Although he was evidently willing to work, lack of food made him weak and listless, and depression was sapping his will to do something to solve his problem.

The idea of a nutrition-based poverty trap, which Pak Solhin explained to us, is very old. Its first formal statement in economics dates from The human body needs a certain number of calories just to survive.

So when someone is very poor, all the food he or she can afford is barely enough to allow for going through the motions of living not eating enough when we met him, but he was eating enough to survive; why would it not pay someone to offer him the extra bit of nutrition that would make him productive in return for a full day's work? More generally, although a hunger-based poverty trap is certainly a logical possibility, how relevant is it in practice, for most poor people today?

One hidden assumption in our description of the poverty trap is that the poor eat as much as they can. And indeed, it would be the obvious implication of an S-shaped curve based on a basic physiological mechanism: If there was any chance that by eating a bit more, the poor could start doing meaningful work and get out of the poverty trap zone, then they should eat as much as possible. Yet, this is not what we see.

Most people living with less than 99 cents a day do not seem to act as if they are starving. If they were, surely they would put every available penny into buying more calories. But they do not. In our eighteen-country data set on the lives of the poor, food represents from 36 to 79 percent of consump-tion among the rural extremely poor, and 53 to 74 percent among their urban counterparts. The poor seem to have many choices, and they don't elect to spend as much as they can on food.

This is evident from looking at how poor people spend any extra money that they happen upon. Although they clearly have some unavoidable expenses they need clothes, medicines, and so forth to take care of first, if their livelihoods depended on getting extra calories, one would imagine that when a little bit more spendable money is available, it would all go into food.

The food budget should go up proportionally faster than total spending since both go up by the same amount, and food is only a part of the total budget, it increases by a bigger proportion. However, this does not seem to be the case. In the Indian state of Maharashtra, in much before India's recent successes-a majority of households then lived on 99 cents per person per day or less , even for the very poorest group, a 1 percent increase in overall expenditure translated into about a 0.

The Maharashtra case is pretty typical of the relationship between income and food expenditures the world over: Even among the very poor, food expenditures increase much less than one for one with the budget. Equally remarkable, even the money that people spend on food is not spent to maximize the intake of calories or micronutrients. When very poor people get a chance to spend a little bit more on food, they don't put everything into getting more calories.

Instead, they buy better-tasting, more expensive calories. For the poorest group in Maharashtra in , out of every additional rupee spent on food when income rose, about half went into purchasing more calories, but the rest went into more expensive calories.

In terms of calories per rupee, the millets jowar and bajra were clearly the best buy. Yet only about two-thirds of the total spending on grains was on these grains, while another 30 percent was spent on rice and wheat, which cost on average about twice as much per calorie.

In addition, the poor spent almost 5 percent of their total budget on sugar, which is both more expensive than grains as a source of calories and bereft of other nutritional value. Robert Jensen and Nolan Miller found a particularly striking example of the "flight to quality" in food consumption. We usually expect that when the price of something goes down, people buy more of it.

The opposite happened. Households that received subsidies for rice or wheat consumed less of those two items and ate more shrimp and meat, even though their staples now cost less.

Remarkably, overall, the caloric intake of those who received the subsidy did not increase and may even have decreased , despite the fact that their purchasing power had increased. Neither did the nutritional content improve in any other sense. The likely explanation is that because the staple formed such a large part of the household budget, the subsidies had made them richer: If the consumption of the staple is associated with being poor say, because it is cheap but not particularly tasty , feeling richer might actually have made them consume less of it.

Once again, this suggests that at least among these very poor urban households, getting more calories was not a priority: Getting better-tasting ones was. The standard media story about it is about the rapid rise of obesity and diabetes as the urban uppermiddle classes get richer. However, Angus Deaton and Jean Dreze have shown that the real story of nutrition in India over the last quarter century is not that Indians are becoming fatter: It is that they are in fact eating less and less.

Today, more than three-fourths of the population live in households whose per capita calorie consumption is less than 2, calories in urban areas and 2, in rural areas-numbers that are often cited as "minimum requirements" in India for individuals engaged in manual labor. It is still the case that richer people eat more than poorer people. But at all levels of income, the share of the budget devoted to food has declined.

Moreover, the composition of the food basket has changed, so that the same amount of money is now spent on more expensive edibles. The change is not driven by declining incomes; by all accounts, real incomes are increasing. Yet, though Indians are richer, they eat so much less at each level of income that they eat less on average today than they used to. Nor is it because of rising food prices-between the early s and , food prices declined relative to the prices of other things, both in rural and urban India.

Although food prices have increased again since , the decline in calorie consumption happened precisely when the price of food was going down. So the poor, even those whom the Food and Agriculture Organization would classify as hungry on the basis of what they eat, do not seem to want to eat much more even when they can. Indeed, they seem to be eating less. What could be going on? The natural place to start to unravel the mystery is to assume that the poor must know what they are doing. After all, they are the ones who eat and work.

If they could indeed be tremendously more productive, and earn much more by eating more, then they probably would when they had the chance. So could it be that eating more doesn't actually make us particularly more productive, and as a result, there is no nutrition-based poverty trap? One reason the poverty trap might not exist is that most people have enough to eat.

At least in terms of food availability, today we live in a world that is capable of feeding every person that lives on the planet. On the occasion of the World Food Summit in , the FAO estimated that world food production in that year was enough to provide at least 2, calories per person per day. One study finds that potatoes may have been responsible for 12 percent of the global increase in population between and There is no absolute scarcity. It is true that if I eat a lot more than I need or, more plausibly, turn more of the corn into biofuels so that I can heat my pool, then there will be less for everybody else.

Using price data from the Philippines, we calculated the cost of the cheapest diet sufficient to give 2, calories, including 10 percent calories from protein and 15 percent calories from fat. It would cost only 21 cents at PPP, very affordable even for someone living on 99 cents a day. The catch is, it would involve eating only bananas and eggs But it seems that so long as people are prepared to eat bananas and eggs when they need to, we should find very few people stuck on the left part of the S-shaped curve, where they cannot earn enough to be functional.

This is consistent with evidence from Indian surveys in which people were asked whether they had enough to eat i. The percentage of people who consider that they do not have enough food has dropped dramatically over time: from 17 percent in to 2 percent in So, perhaps people eat less because they are less hungry. And perhaps they are really less hungry, despite eating fewer calories. It could be that because of improvements in water and sanitation, they are leaking fewer calories in bouts of diarrhea and other ailments.

Or maybe they are less hungry because of the decline of heavy physical work-with the availability of drinking water in the village, women do not need to carry heavy loads for long distances; improvements in transportation have reduced the need to travel on foot; in even the poorest village, flour is now milled by the village miller using a motorized mill, instead of women grinding it by hand.

Using the average calorie requirements calculated by the Indian Council of Medical Research for people engaged in heavy, moderate, or light activity, Deaton and Dreze note that the decline in calorie consumption over the last twenty-five years could be entirely explained by a modest decrease in the number of people engaged in physically heavy work for a large part of the day. If most people are at the point where they are not starving, it is possible that the productivity gains from consuming more calories are relatively modest for them.

It would then be understandable if people chose to do something else with their money, or move away from eggs and bananas toward a more exciting diet. Many years ago, John Strauss was looking for a clear case to demonstrate the role of calories in productivity. He settled on self-employed farmers in Sierra Leone, because they really have to work hard.

Thus, even if people doubled their food consumption, their income would only increase by 40 percent. Furthermore, the shape of the relationship between calories and productivity was not an S-shape, but an inverted L-shape, as in Figure 2 in the previous chapter: The largest gains are obtained at low levels of food consumption. There is no steep jump in income once people start eating enough. This suggests that the very poor benefit more from eating extra calories than the less poor.

This is precisely the type of situation where we would not see a poverty trap. So it is not because they don't eat enough that most people stay poor. This is not to say that the logic of the hunger-based poverty trap is flawed.

The idea that better nutrition would propel someone on the path to prosperity was almost surely very important at some point in history, and it may still be important in some circumstances today.

The Nobel Prize Laureate and economic historian Robert Fogel calculated that in Europe during the Renaissance and the Middle Ages, food production did not provide enough calories to sustain a full working population. This could explain why there were large numbers of beg-gars-they were literally incapable of any work. Witches were most likely to be single women, particularly widows. The logic of the S-shape suggests that when resources are tight, it makes "economic sense" to sacrifice some people, so that the rest have enough food to be able to work and earn enough to survive.

During droughts in India in the s, little girls in landless households were much more likely to die than boys, but boys' and girls' death rates were not very different when there was normal rainfall. So it is not that the lack of food could not be a problem or isn't a problem from time to time, but the world we live in today is for the most part too rich for it to be a big part of the story of the persistence of poverty.

This is of course different during natural or man-made disasters, or in famines that kill and weaken millions. As Amartya Sen has shown, however, most recent famines have been caused not by lack of food availability but by institutional failures that led to poor distribution of the available food, or even hoarding and storage in the face of starvation elsewhere.

Can we assume that the poor, though they may be eating little, do eat as much as they need to? It is hard to avoid the feeling that the story does not add up.

Can it be true that the poorest individuals in India are cutting back on food because they don't need the calories, given that they live in families that consume around 1, calories per capita per day to start with? After all, 1, calories is the famous semi-starvation diet, recommended for those who want rapid weight loss; 1, does not seem too far from there. According to the Centers for Disease Control, the average American male consumed 2, calories per day in But doesn't that just push the question back one level?

Why are the poorest in India so small? Indeed, why are all South Asians so scrawny? The standard way to measure nourishment status is by the Body Mass Index BMI , which is essentially a way to scale weight by height i.

The international cutoff for being malnourished is a BMI of By this measure, 33 percent of men and 36 percent of women in India were undernourished in , down from 49 percent for both in Among the eighty-three countries that have demographic and health survey data, only Eritrea has more undernourished adult women. Could this be something purely genetic about South Asians, like dark eyes or black hair, but irrelevant for their success in the world?

After all, even the children of South Asian immigrants in the United Kingdom or the United States are smaller than Caucasian or black children. It turns out, however, that two generations of living in the West without intermarriage with other communities is enough to make the grandchildren of South Asian immigrants more or less the same height as other ethnicities. So although genetic makeup is certainly important at the individual level, the genetic differences in height between populations are believed to be minimal.

If the children of first-generation mothers are still small, it is partly because women who were themselves malnourished in childhood tend to have smaller children. Therefore, if South Asians are small, it is probably because they, and their parents, did not get as much nourishment as their counterparts in other countries. And indeed, everything suggests that children are very badly nourished in India. The usual measure of how well a child has been fed through the childhood years is height, compared to the international average height for that age.

Roughly half the children under five are stunted, which means that they are far below the norm. One-fourth of them are severely stunted, representing extreme nutritional deprivation.

The children are also extraordinarily underweight given their height: About one in five children under three is wasted, which means they fall below the international definition of severe malnourishment. What makes these facts more striking is that the stunting and wasting rates in sub-Saharan Africa, undoubtedly the poorest area of the world, are only about half those in India.

But once again, should we care? Is being small a problem, in and of itself? Well, there are the Olympic Games. India, a country with a billion inhabitants, has won an average of 0. To put these numbers in perspective, China has won medals in eight games, at an average of Yet India has ten times as many people as all but six of those countries. Of course India is poor, but not as poor as it used to be, and not nearly as poor as Cameroon, Ethiopia, Ghana, Haiti, Kenya, Mozambique, Nigeria, Tanzania, and Uganda, each of which, per head, has more than ten times India's medal count.

Indeed, no country that has fewer medals per Olympics than India is even one-tenth of its size, with two notable exceptions-Pakistan and Bangladesh. Bangladesh, in particular, is the only country of over million people that has never won an Olympic medal. The next largest such country is Nepal.

There is clearly a pattern. One could perhaps blame the South Asian obsession with cricket-that colonial cousin of baseball that baffles most Americans-but if cricket is absorbing all the sporting talent of one-fourth of the world's population, the results are really not that impressive. South Asians have never had the dominance over cricket that Australia, England, and even the tiny West Indies had in their heydays, despite their intense fealty to the sport and their massive size advantage-Bangladesh, for example, is bigger than England, South Africa, Australia, New Zealand, and the West Indies put together.

Given that child malnutrition is one other area where South Asia really stands out, it seems plausible that these two facts-wasted children and Olympian failure-have something to do with each other.

The Olympics are not the only place where height plays a role. In poor countries and rich countries alike, taller people do earn more. It has long been debated whether this is because height really matters for productivity-it could be discrimination against shorter people, for example. But a recent paper by Anne Case and Chris Paxson made some progress in nailing down what explains this relationship.

They show that in the United Kingdom and the United States, the effect of height is entirely accounted for by differences in IQ: When we compare people who have the same IQ, there is no relationship between height and earning.

And it is because they are smarter that they earn more. Of course, there are many not-so-tall people who are very bright because they have reached the height they were meant to reach , but overall, tall people do better in life, because they are visibly more likely to have reached their genetic potential both in height and in intelligence.

The study, when reported by Reuters under the notso-subtle headline "Taller People Are Smarter-Study," created a firestorm.

Case and Paxson were deluged by hostile e-mails. In Kenya, children who were given deworming pills in school for two years went to school longer and earned, as young adults, 20 percent more than children in comparable schools who received deworming for just one year: Worms contribute to anemia and general malnutrition, essentially because they compete with the child for nutrients.

They con-clude: "Undernourished children are more likely to become short adults, to have lower educational achievement, and to give birth to smaller infants.

Undernutrition is also associated with lower economic status in adulthood. David Barker's theory that conditions in utero have long-term impact on a child's life chances. In fact, based on their estimates, the study concludes that if every mother were to take iodine capsules, there would be a 7.

This, in turn, could affect the child's productivity throughout his or her life. Although we saw that the impact of just increasing calories on productivity may not be very large per se, there are some ways to improve nutrition even for adults that will much more than pay for themselves. The one that we know most about is iron to treat anemia. In many Asian countries, including India and Indonesia, anemia is a major health problem. Six percent of men and 38 percent of women in Indonesia are anemic.

The corresponding numbers in India are 24 percent and 56 percent. Anemia is associated with low aerobic capacity, general weakness and lethargy, and in some cases especially for pregnant women it can be life-threatening. The Work and Iron Status Evaluation WISE study in Indonesia provided randomly chosen men and women in rural Indonesia with regular iron supplementation for several months, while the comparison group received a placebo.

The puzzle is that people do not seem to want more food, and yet more food and especially more judiciously purchased food would probably make them, and almost certainly their children, significantly more successful in life. The key investments that would achieve this are not expensive. Most mothers could surely afford iodized salt, which is now standard in many parts of the world, or one dose of iodine every two years at 51 cents per dose.

In Kenya, when International Child Support, the NGO that was running the deworming program, asked the parents in some schools to pay a few cents for deworming their children, almost all of them refused, which deprived their children of hundreds of dollars of extra earning over their lifetime. Who Knew? Why did anemic Indonesian workers not buy iron-fortified fish sauce on their own? One answer is that it is not clear that the additional productivity translates into higher earnings if employers do not know that a wellnourished worker is more productive.

Employers may not realize that their employees are more productive now because they have eaten more, or better. The Indonesian study found a significant increase in earnings only among self-employed workers. If the employers pay everyone the same flat wage, there would be no reason to eat more to get stronger. In the Philippines, a study found that workers who worked both for a piece rate and for a flat wage ate 25 percent more food on days they worked for piece rate where effort mattered, since the more they worked, the more they got paid.

This does not explain why all pregnant women in India aren't using only iodine-fortified salt, which is now available for purchase in every village. A possibility is that people may not realize the value of feeding themselves and their children better. The importance of micronutrients was not fully understood, even by scientists, until relatively recently. Although micronutrients are cheap and can sometimes lead to a large increase in lifetime income, it is necessary to know exactly what to eat or what pills to take.

Not everyone has the information, even in the United States. Moreover, people tend to be suspicious of outsiders who tell them that they should change their diet, probably because they like what they eat. When rice prices went up sharply in , the chief minister of West Bengal suggested that eating less rice and more vegetables would be both good for people's health and easier on their budget.

This set off a flurry of protests, and the chief minister was greeted by protesters with garlands of vegetables wherever he went.

Yet he was probably right. Understanding the importance of popular support, Antoine Parmentier, an eighteenth-century French pharmacist who was an early fan of the potato, clearly anticipating resistance, offered the public a set of recipes he had invented using potatoes, including the classic dish Hachis Parmentier essentially what the British call shepherd's pie, a layered casserole composed of ground meat with a covering of mashed potatoes.

He thereby set off a trajectory that ultimately led, through many twists and turns, to the invention of "freedom fries. Iodine might make your children smarter, but the difference is not huge though a number of small differences may add up to something big and in most cases you will not find out either way for many years. Consequently, it is no surprise that the poor choose their foods not mainly for their cheap prices and nutritional values, but for how good they taste.

George Orwell, in his masterful description of the life of poor Brit-ish workers in The Road to Wigan Pier, observes: The basis of their diet, therefore, is white bread and Margarine, corned beef, sugared tea, and potato-an appalling diet. Would it not be better if they spent more money on wholesome things like oranges and wholemeal bread, or if they even, like the reader of the New Statesman, saved on fuel and ate their carrots raw?

Yes it would, but the point is, no human being would ever do such a thing. The ordinary human being would sooner starve than live on brown bread and raw carrots.

And the peculiar evil is this, that the less money you have the less you are inclined to spend it on wholesome food. A millionaire may enjoy breakfasting off orange juice and Ryvita biscuits; an unemployed man does not. When you are unemployed, you don't want to eat dull wholesome food. You want to eat something a little tasty. There is always some cheap pleasant thing to tempt you. This is one of the running themes in this book.

Another explanation for their eating habits is that other things are more important in the lives of the poor than food. It has been widely documented that poor people in the developing world spend large amounts on weddings, dowries, and christenings, probably in part as a result of the compulsion not to lose face.

The cost of weddings in India is well-known, but there are also less cheerful occasions when the family is compelled to throw a lavish party. In South Africa, social norms on how much to spend on funerals were set at a time when most deaths occurred in old age or in infancy. After such a funeral, the family clearly has less to spend, and more family members tend to complain about "lack of food," even when the deceased was not earning before he died, which suggests that funeral costs are responsible.

The more expensive the funeral, the more depressed the adults are one year later, and the more likely it is that children have dropped out of school. In , the king simply banned lavish funerals 32 and announced that if a family was found to have slaughtered a cow for their funeral, they would have to give one cow to the chief's herd.

The SACC, rather more soberly, called for a regulation of the funeral industry, which, they felt, was putting pressure on families to spend more than they could afford. The decision to spend money on things other than food may not be due entirely to social pressure. We asked Oucha Mbarbk, a man we met in a remote village in Morocco, what he would do if he had more money. He said he would buy more food.

Then we asked him what he would do if he had even more money. He said he would buy bettertasting food. We were starting to feel very bad for him and his family, when we noticed a television, a parabolic antenna, and a DVD player in the room where we were sitting. We asked him why he had bought all these things if he felt the family did not have enough to eat. He laughed, and said, "Oh, but television is more important than food!

Life can be quite boring in a village. There is no movie theater, no concert hall, no place to sit and watch interesting strangers go by.

And not a lot of work, either. Oucha and two of his neighbors, who were with him during the interview, had worked about seventy days in agriculture and about thirty days in construction that year. For the rest of the year, they took care of their cattle and waited for jobs to materialize. This left plenty of time to watch television. These three men all lived in small houses without water or sanitation. They struggled to find work, and to give their children a good education. But they all had a television, a parabolic antenna, a DVD player, and a cell phone.

Generally, it is clear that things that make life less boring are a priority for the poor. This may be a television, or a little bit of something special to eat-or just a cup of sugary tea. Even Pak Solhin had a television, although it was not working when we visited him. Festivals may be seen in this light as well. Where televisions or radios are not available, it is easy to see why the poor often seek out the distraction of a special family celebration of some kind, a religious observance, or a daughter's wedding.

In our eighteen-country data set, it is clear that the poor spend more on festivals when they are less likely to have a radio or a television. In Udaipur, India, where almost no one has a television, the extremely poor spend 14 percent of their budget on festivals which includes both lay and religious occasions. By contrast, in Nicaragua, where 56 percent of rural poor households have a radio and 21 percent own a television, very few households report spending anything on festivals.

Today, television signals reach into remote areas, and there are more things to buy, even in remote villages. Cell phones work almost everywhere, and talk time is extremely cheap by global standards. This would also explain why countries with a large domestic economy, where a lot of consumer goods are available cheaply, like India and Mexico, tend to be the countries where food spending is the lowest.

Every village in India has at least one small shop, usually more, with shampoo sold in individual sachets, cigarettes by the stick, very cheap combs, pens, toys, or candies, whereas in a country like Papua New Guinea, where the share of food in the household budget is above 70 percent it is 50 percent in India , there may be fewer things available to the poor.

Orwell captured this phenomenon as well in The Road to Wigan Pier when he described how poor families managed to survive the depression. Instead of raging against their destiny, they have made things tolerable by reducing their standards. But they don't necessarily reduce their standards by cutting out luxuries and concentrating on necessities; more often it is the other way around-the more natural way, if you come to think of it-hence the fact that in a decade of unparalleled depression, the consumption of all cheap luxuries has increased.

They are carefully thought out, and reflect strong compulsions, whether internally driven or externally imposed. Oucha Mbarbk did not buy his TV on credit-he saved up over many months to scrape enough money together, just as the mother in India starts saving for her eight-year-old daughter's wedding some ten years or more into the future, by buying a small piece of jewelry here and a stainless steel bucket there.

We are often inclined to see the world of the poor as a land of missed opportunities and to wonder why they don't put these purchases on hold and invest in what would really make their lives better. The poor, on the other hand, may well be more skeptical about supposed opportunities and the possibility of any radical change in their lives. They often behave as if they think that any change that is significant enough to be worth sacrificing for will simply take too long.

This could explain why they focus on the here and now, on living their lives as pleasantly as possible, celebrating when occasion demands it. We opened this chapter with Pak Solhin, and his view that he was caught in a nutrition-based poverty trap. At the most literal level, the main problem in his case was probably not a lack of calories. The Rakshin Program was providing him with some free rice, and between that and the help his brother was giving him, he would probably have been physically able to work in the field or on a construction site.

Our reading of the evidence suggests that most adults, even the very poor, are outside of the nutrition poverty trap zone: They can easily eat as much as they need to be physically productive. This was probably the case with Pak Solhin. This not to say that he was not trapped. But his problem may have come from the fact that his job had vanished, and he was too old to be taken as an apprentice on a construction site. His situation was almost surely made worse by the fact that he was depressed, which made it difficult for him to do anything at all.

The fact that the basic mechanics of a nutrition-based poverty trap do not seem to be at work for adults does not mean that nutrition is not a problem for the poor. But the problem may be less the quantity of food than its quality, and in particular the shortage of micronutrients.

The benefits of good nutrition may be particularly strong for two sets of people who do not decide what they eat: unborn babies and young children. In fact, there may well be an S-shaped relationship between their parent's income and the eventual income of these children, caused by childhood nutrition. That is because a child who got the proper nutrients in utero or during early childhood will earn more money every year of his or her life: This adds up to large benefits over a lifetime.

This suggests that governments and international institutions need to completely rethink food policy. Although this may be bad news for American farmers, the solution is not to simply supply more food grains, which is what most food security programs are currently designed to do. The poor like subsidized grains, but as we discussed earlier, giving them more does little to persuade them to eat better, especially since the main problem is not calories, but other nutrients.

It also is probably not enough just to provide the poor with more money, and even rising incomes will probably not lead to better nutrition in the short run.

As we saw in India, the poor do not eat any more or any better when their income goes up; there are too many other pressures and desires competing with food. In contrast, the social returns of directly investing in children and pregnant mother nutrition are tremendous. This can be done by giving away fortified foods to pregnant mothers and parents of small children, by treating children for worms in preschool or at school, by providing them with meals rich in micronutrients, or even by giving parents incentives to consume nutritional supplements.

All of this is already being done in some countries. The government of Kenya is now systematically deworming children in school. In Colombia, micronutrient packets are sprinkled on kids' meals in preschool. In Mexico, social welfare payments come with free nutritional supplements for the family.

Developing ways to pack foods that people like to eat with additional nutrients, and coming up with new strains of nutritious and tasty crops that can be grown in a wider range of environments, need to become priorities for food technology, on an equal footing with raising productivity.

We do see some instances of this across the world, pushed by organizations such as the Micronutrient Initiative and HarvestPlus: A variety of orange sweet potatoes richer in beta carotene than the native yam suitable for Africa was recently introduced in Uganda and Mozambique.

But there are all too many instances where food policy remains hung up on the idea that all the poor need is cheap grain. Health is an area of great promise but also great frustration.

There seems to be plenty of "low-hanging fruit" available, from vaccines to bed nets, that could save lives at a minimal cost, but all too few people make use of such preventive technologies. Government health workers, who are in charge of delivering basic health-care services in most countries, are often blamed for this failure, not entirely unfairly, as we will see.

They, on the other hand, insist that plucking these low-hanging fruits is much harder than it seems. In winter in the beautiful town of Udaipur in western India, we had an animated discussion with a group of government nurses. They were very upset with us because we were involved in a project that aimed to get them to come to work more often. At some point in the proceedings, one of them got so exasperated that she decided to be blunt: The job was essentially pointless anyway, she announced.

When a child came to them with diarrhea, all they could offer the mother was a packet of oral rehyd-ration solution or ORS, a mixture of salt, sugar, potassium chloride, and an antacid to be mixed with water and drunk by the child.

But most mothers didn't believe that ORS could do any good. They wanted what they thought was the right treatment-an antibiotic or an intravenous drip. Once a mother was sent away from the health center with just a packet of ORS, the nurses told us, she never came back. Every year, they saw scores of children die from diarrhea, but they felt utterly powerless. Of the 9 million children who die before their fifth birthdays each year, the vast majority are poor children from South Asia and sub-Saharan Africa, and roughly one in five dies of diarrhea.

Efforts are under way to develop and distribute a vaccine against rotavirus, the virus responsible for many though not all of the cases of diarrhea. But three "miracle drugs" could already save most of these children: chlorine bleach, for purifying water; and salt and sugar, the key ingredients of the rehydration solution ORS. Yet neither chlorine nor ORS is used very much. In Zambia, thanks to the efforts of Population Service International PSI , a large organization that markets it at sub-sidized prices worldwide, chlorine is cheap and widely available.

But only 10 percent of families use it. Bleach and ORS are not unique examples. There is other relatively "low-hanging fruit" with promise to improve health and save many lives. These are cheap and simple technologies that, if properly utilized, would save much in resources in terms of extra days worked, less antibiotics used, stronger bodies, and so on. They could pay for themselves, in addition to saving lives.

But too many of these fruits are left unpicked. It is not that people don't care about their health. They do, and they devote considerable resources to it.



Christmas Wood Craft Plans Zip
Hammer Toe Vs Mallet Toe 80
Douper Soft Close Lid Support Hinges 30
Best 2 On 2 Battle Rap

Author: admin | 29.09.2020



Comments to «Amana Raised Panel Bits Young»

  1. Dust collectors and cyclone dust connectivity requirements.

    DarkSteel

    29.09.2020 at 14:50:18

  2. The crest, however outside of the stretchers and.

    I_Like_KekS

    29.09.2020 at 22:34:31

  3. Line represents build beautiful a wooden magazine holder can really bring a space together.

    aftos

    29.09.2020 at 10:48:22

  4. Gauge metal flag backing create.

    Posthumosty

    29.09.2020 at 22:49:44